MPIfG Working Paper 06/7, October 2006
Trade Policy Lobbying in the European Union: Who
Captures Whom?
Cornelia Woll
,
Centre d'Etudes et de Recherches Internationales (CERI),
Sciences Po Paris
Chapter prepared for David Coen and Jeremy
Richardson (eds.), Lobbying in the European Union: Institutions, Actors and
Issues. Oxford University Press, forthcoming. I would like to thank Holger
Döring and Armin Schäfer for their helpful remarks.
Abstract
What role do firms play in the making of EU trade policy?
This article surveys the policy domain and lays out the instruments firms can
employ to influence decisions on trade. It underlines that European trade policy
is characterized by a high degree of institutional complexity, which firms have
to manage in order to be successful. In particular, the European Commission
works intensively to solicit business input in order to gain bargaining leverage
vis-à-vis third countries and the EU member states. This reverse lobbying
creates a two-channel logic of trade policy lobbying in the EU. Corporate actors
have a very good chance of working closely with the European Commission if they
can propose pan-European trade policy solutions. This can be either trade
liberalization or EU-wide regulatory restrictions on trade. Demands for
traditional protectionist measures, especially those that reveal national
interest divergences, are difficult to defend at the supranational level.
Protectionist lobbying therefore goes through the national route, with corporate
actors working to block liberalization by affecting the consensus in the Council
of Ministers. The chapter illustrates this two-channel logic by studying
business–government interactions in agricultural trade, textiles and clothing,
financial services, and telecommunication services.
Zusammenfassung
Welchen Einfluss haben Unternehmen auf die
europäische Handelspolitik? Durch einen Überblick des Politikfelds analysiert
der Artikel Instrumente, mit denen Unternehmen in der EU Lobbyismus betreiben
können. Vielen Firmen werden allerdings nicht von sich aus aktiv. Im Gegenteil,
die Europäische Kommission bemüht sich aktiv um die Zusammenarbeit der
Unternehmen, da sie dadurch ihre Verhandlungsposition vis-à-vis Mitgliedsstaaten
und Drittstaaten stärken kann. Dieses umgekehrte Lobbying hat Folgen für die
Inhalte der Unternehmensforderungen im Bereich Handelspolitik. Wirtschaftliche
Akteure können ein gutes Arbeitsverhältnis mit der Europäischen Kommission
aufbauen, wenn sie gesamteuropäische Konzepte verfolgen, sei es
Handelsliberalisierung oder EU-weite Regulierung. Nationaler Protektionismus
kann europäische Entscheidungsfindung blockieren, so dass merkantilistische
Anfragen an die nationalen Regierungen gerichtet werden müssen, die diese dann
durch den Rat der Minister voranbringen können. Der Artikel illustriert diese
zweigleisige Lobbyingstrategien in der Landwirtschaft, dem Textilhandel, dem
Finanzdienstleistungssektor und der Telekommunikation.
Introduction
References
Introduction
Trade policy is a classic field for the study of private influence on
policy-making. Firms and industries can gain clear advantages by protecting
their markets from foreign competition or by gaining access to other countries.
A large portion of the literature on international political economy therefore
explains policy choices with reference to the demands of constituent interests (see
Frieden and Martin 2002). For anybody interested in business lobbying, trade
policy would seem to be the most appropriate place to start.
And yet, comparing trade policy lobbying in the US and the EU leaves many
observers surprised. Aggressive business lobbying on trade issues is much less
common in Brussels than it is in Washington, D.C. (e.g. Coen 1999; cf. Woll
2006). Shaffer (2003: 6) underlines that US firms and trade associations are
very proactive in business–government relations on trade policy. This "bottom-up" approach contrasts with the
"top down" EU approach where public
authority, in particular the European Commission, plays the predominant
entrepreneurial role.
While the US Trade Representative responded to onslaughts of private sector
lobbying reinforced by congressional phone calls and committee grillings, the
Commission had to contact firms to contact it (Shaffer 2003: 70).
Indeed, we will see that the European Commission has made a concerted effort to
integrate firms and other private actors into the trade policy-making process in
order to gain bargaining leverage not simply vis-à-vis third countries, but also
over its own member states (Van den Hoven 2002). By helping to elaborate policy
solutions, interest group participation increases the legitimacy of the
Commission on external trade issues.
This reverse lobbying is not without consequences. While firms do increasingly
seize the opportunities available to them at the supranational level, EU trade
policy lobbying is marked by a particular logic. Firms face a trade-off between
pressing for their immediate advantages and responding to the interests of the
European Commission, which promises them access to the policy-making process (Broscheid
and Coen 2003). Since the Commission is not immediately accountable to
constituency interests, it can select interest groups and firms that it prefers
to work with and ignore others (Grande 1996). In selecting private partners, the
Commission follows two objectives: first, it requires technical expertise to
advance on its policy proposals (Bouwen 2002); second, and on trade issues in
particular, it is interested in finding pan-European solutions to prevent
disputes between the member states that would risk stalling trade negotiations
(Shaffer 2003: 78-79). When protectionist measures depend on national boundaries,
industry privileges are likely to conflict with the Commission's goals. Firms
therefore have to decide between lobbying for their immediate advantage at the
risk of being ignored and framing their demands in terms of a pan-European
interest even if they are not certain of obtaining an advantage.
This logic creates two distinct channels for trade policy lobbying in the EU. A
firm or industry interested in classic protectionism is most successful when it
uses a national lobbying strategy directed at the member states and ultimately
the Council of Ministers. Supranational lobbying, in turn, requires making
demands with pan-European dimensions. Lobbyists thus have to find ways of
proposing pan-European protectionism, most commonly in the form of pan-European
trade regulation (Young 2004). Alternatively, they can lobby for trade
liberalization in order to establish or maintain contacts with the European
Commission and then hope to integrate more precise demands in the details of
trade regulation or the implementation of agreements.
By studying the Europeanization of trade policy and the instruments firms employ
to affect EU trade policy, a first part of this paper underlines the complexity
individual firms have to manage in order to influence the Community stance on
international trade negotiations. As an illustration of the EU trade policy
lobbying logic, a second part then turns to concrete policy examples and
compares the protectionist lobbying on agriculture and textiles and clothing
with the lobbying on service trade liberalization in financial services and
telecommunications. The conclusion discusses the extent to which the findings on
business lobbying have implications for other actors seeking to affect trade
policy, most notably NGOs or public interest groups.
1 Trade policy lobbying in the multi-level system
Trade policy is one of the most integrated policy
areas in the EU, and yet the struggle over the competence distribution between
the supranational institutions and the member states is crucial for
understanding lobbying in this domain. Before turning to the key instruments for
corporate lobbying on EU trade, it is therefore necessary to understand the
Europeanization of trade policy and the history of competence delegation from
the member states to the EU Institutions.
1.1 The integration of trade policy-making
The common commercial policy is as old as
the European Economic Community itself. With the Treaty of Rome in
1957, member states agreed that a customs union requires a common
external tariff, common trade agreements with third countries and
uniform application across member states. On these issues, they
therefore granted the European institutions the right to speak on their
behalf in external trade negotiations. Initially, this authority
applied to tariff rates, anti-dumping and subsidies, which were indeed
the main stakes in early multilateral trade negotiations under the
General Agreement on Tariffs and Trade (GATT). During the Tokyo Round
of GATT (1973-9) and especially during the Uruguay Round (1986-94),
non-tariff barriers to trade started to gain importance, including
health, environmental and social aspects of trade policy, and the
domestic regulatory issues applying to the trade in services. European
trade authority did not apply to many of these issues, which pushed the
Community to redefine trade competences and the degree of delegation
from the member states to the EU. In particular, it stirred up a debate
over which issues should fall under "exclusive" or "mixed" competence
(Meunier and Nicolaïdis 1999; Meunier 2000a).
Mixed competence means that trade authority
is delegated on an ad hoc basis to the Community. The setting of
objectives and the ratification of the negotiation results are subject
to a unanimous vote by the Council, whereas both require only a
qualified majority under exclusive competence. Over time, many areas of
mixed competence have been dealt with pragmatically at first, by
letting the Commission negotiate without fully resolving the competence
dispute. For the results to be adopted, however, the legal competence
question has become pressing. When the European Court of Justice
decided against an automatic expansion of trade competences in 1994,
the Commission and the member states first agreed on a code of conduct
and later adopted a special competence transfer procedure in 1996
(Meunier 2000b: 338-40). It was not until 2003 that the Treaty of Nice
finally amended Article 133 and provided for the exclusive competence
over services and intellectual property rights, with the exception of
cultural and audio-visual services. The struggle underlines how heavily
disputed the transfer of authority is. Delegation is a delicate matter,
even in this highly integrated policy domain, and control mechanisms
employed by member states are tight (De Bièvre and Dür 2005).
The various control mechanisms become
evident when one considers the different stages in the trade
policy-making cycle. Woolcock (2000) distinguishes between (1) the
setting of objectives, (2) the conduct of negotiations and (3) the
adoption of results. The negotiation objectives are decided by the
General Affairs Council of foreign ministers on the basis of a
Commission proposal. Long before the formal adoption of a mandate, the
Commission submits the proposal to the member states or, more
precisely, to senior national trade officials representing their
governments on the Article 133 Committee (see Johnson 1998).
Discussions during this phase are crucial, since the Commission can use
the Article 133 Committee "as a sounding board to ensure that it is on
the right track" (Shaffer 2003: 79). Trying to achieve a consensus on
the mandate, the Article 133 Committee examines and amends the proposal
before handing it to the Committee of Permanent Representatives
(COREPER) and eventually the Council. Neither the European Parliament
nor the general public participate in these early negotiations, which
take place behind closed doors in order to shield the negotiation
objectives from the trading partners. Woolcock (2000: 380) underlines
how sharply the role of the European Parliament contrasts with the role
of the US Congress. Indeed, constituents lobbying their representatives
have more direct control over the negotiating mandate in the US, where
Congress can grant or withhold negotiation authority.
The conduct of negotiations is the
responsibility of the Commission, but even in areas of exclusive
competence, consultation with the member states is crucial. The Article
133 Committee closely follows negotiations and the EU negotiation team
meets daily with member state representatives. On sensitive issues such
as service trade liberalization, trading partners have jokingly
remarked that the Commission negotiates more with the member states
than with the rest of the world (Woll 2004: 227). The Commission,
furthermore, tries to keep the External Economic Relations Committee of
the European Parliament informed, even though the Parliament has no
speaking rights during negotiations. Results are adopted by the General
Affairs Council either by qualified majority voting under exclusive
competence or by unanimous decision under mixed competence. In
practice, however, consensus decisions are the norm (Woolcock 2000:
384).
The importance of consensus between the
member states applies equally to dispute settlement procedures. The
most common way to bring a dispute to the WTO is for the Commission to
initiate a case after consultation with the Article 133 Committee.
Formal procedure requires conflictual issues to be transferred to
COREPER and subsequently to the Council, should all other instances
fail to resolve the dispute. In all the time the WTO has employed the
dispute settlement procedure, this has only happened once. According to
Shaffer (2003: 80)
"neither
committee members nor the Commission wish to transfer decision-making
authority on trade matters from themselves, who are trade experts, to
the Council, which consists of foreign affairs ministers."
To summarize, all stages of trade
policy-making are characterized by an explicit desire to achieve and
maintain consensus between the member states. The Commission cannot
negotiate effectively if the EU member states are not behind the
Community objectives. The interlocking of member state control and
Commission authority are thus the two important dimensions of trade
policy-making that interest groups and firms need to take into account
if they wish to lobby effectively.
1.2 Instruments and venues for corporate lobbying
Consultation with private actors happens at various
stages of EU trade policy-making. Business interests, furthermore, affect the
use of instruments of commercial defence, with which the Community tries to
ensure equal competition for European and foreign firms. During trade
negotiations and with respect to instruments of commercial defence, the
solicitation by the Commission plays a key role in shaping the access of private
actors to the policy-making process.
1.2.1 Trade policy consultation with private actors
Even though discussions between the Commission and the Article 133 Committee
on negotiation objectives are not public, the Commission consults extensively
with firms, interest groups and NGOs in order to define specific stakes in its
proposal. The EU consultation procedure is less formal than the system of Trade
Advisory Committees in the US, but the Commission DG Trade and DG Industry
maintain stable relations with groups such as the Union of Industries of the
European Community (UNICE) or sectoral business associations. In 1998, the
Commission tried to formalize its consultation and include a broader range of
interest groups by instituting a Civil Society Dialogue on the upcoming round of
negotiations (Van den Hoven 2002; De Bièvre and Dür forthcoming). Both business
interests and public interest groups now participate in the Civil Society
Dialogue. However, unlike the US advisory system, the Commission is under no
legal obligation to consult with the Civil Society Dialogue or to take its
reports into consideration.
Yet input from interest groups is valuable to the European Commission because it
can help strengthen its negotiation stances vis-à-vis the member states and its
trading partners. During the Uruguay Round, American negotiators cooperated
closely with US industry representatives. By contrast, the European business
community was largely absent from the negotiations, despite the importance of
multilateral trading stakes. Only UNICE declared in favour of the Commission
position, and Jacques Delors complained openly about the lack of business
support (Grant 1994: 83-5; Van den Hoven 2002: 10).
Integrating business interests into the
formulation of trade objectives therefore became an important goal for
the European Commission in the 1990s. One of the most noted initiatives
was the Transatlantic Business Dialogue (TABD), founded by the US
Secretary of Commerce Ron Brown and European Trade Commissioner Sir
Leon Brittan in 1995. The aim of the TABD was to bring together CEOs of
American and European companies so that they could "pre-negotiate"
issues relevant to transatlantic trade (Coen and Grant 2000; Cowles
2001). Similarly, the Commission encouraged the creation of other
consultative associations, such as the European Service Forum, launched
in January 1999. Initiatives such as the Civil Society Dialogue, the
TABD or the European Service Forum illustrate the extent to which the
Commission solicits participation from private actors and is willing to
listen to their suggestions.
However, individual groups have few means of putting direct pressure on the
Commission to ensure that their demands will be taken into account. Within each
member state, they can try to lobby their governments to affect the consensus
between member states and the Commission during all phases of the policy cycle.
They can also contact the European Parliament, which holds hearings and produces
reports on trade issues, but this will do little more than shape the atmosphere
in which EU objectives are determined and monitored (Woolcock 2000: 380). During
the adoption phase, national parliaments and the European Parliament may play a
greater role in the future, especially now that co-decision has been extended by
the Treaty of Amsterdam, but lobbying on trade policy still concentrates on the
interchange between the Commission and member governments.
1.2.2 Instruments of commercial defence
In addition to ongoing trade negotiations, business
lobbying can also target separate administrative procedures to ensure protection
against 'unfair' foreign competition. These instruments of commercial defence
include anti-dumping and countervailing duties and the Trade Barriers Regulation
of 1994. All of these administrative instruments require the identification of
unfair competition practices, for which firms often have better information than
governments. Over time, the EU has therefore tried to facilitate business input,
so as to identify the greatest possible number of trade barriers or obstacles to
competition.
Anti-dumping measures, by far the most commonly used instrument of commercial
defence, seek to punish exporters who sell their goods in the EU below the cost
of their domestic production. The procedure begins with a complaint filed by
industry representatives, which the Commission then decides to pursue or not. In
the event of an investigation, the Commission studies in consultation with the
national authorities whether there is evidence of dumping or injury to a
European industry and seeks proof that the imposition of duties would be in the
'Community interest'. Hearings are held to define the Community interest and to
make it difficult for narrow protectionist interests to pursue anti-dumping
actions (Woolcock 2000: 389-90). In fact, petitioners need to represent 50% of
the injured industry, which makes it hard for individual firms to file a
complaint (De Bièvre 2002: 86). After the imposition of a provisional duty by
the Commission, the Council can decide by simple majority to reject the duty or
to impose definite action.
Until the beginning of the World Trade Organization (WTO), which replaced GATT
in 1995, the commercial policy of the EU was relatively defensive. European
trade officials had simultaneously to respond to demands for protection through
anti-dumping measures and to face the US, which actively sought to dismantle
European trade barriers. Faced with "aggressive unilateralism" from the US (Bhagwati
and Patrick 1991), the EU had sought to create a New Commercial Policy
Instrument in 1984, which tried to emulate US business–government cooperation in
identifying trade barriers. Unlike the US model, the European procedure was
marred with difficulties. In its ten year history, European firms filed only
seven petitions (Shaffer 2003: 84-94). In December 1994, the instrument was
replaced by the Trade Barriers Regulation, which supporters were hoping would
have more teeth. Innovations included the right of individual firms to petition
the Commission directly, as may member governments. Furthermore, the petitioner
no longer needs to provide proof of injury in order to file the complaint. The
Trade Barrier Regulation requires the EU to exhaust all available multilateral
dispute settlement procedures before resorting to unilateral action, which means
that the procedure serves mostly as a means of identifying potential WTO dispute
settlement cases.
Indeed, soliciting industry help in identifying such cases was one of the main
motivations behind the Trade Barrier Regulation. Traditional international trade
disputes were initiated by the Commission in consultation with the Article 133
Committee. Lacking close cooperation with business interests and trade
associations, the EU was much less able to exploit the WTO Dispute Settlement
Body when it was first established in 1995. The US, by contrast, brought several
high-profile cases against the EU, and filed 8 of the first 15 complaints
resulting in panels [1].
Commission officials felt that they needed to show more
initiative and started to work actively to gain industry support and industry's
technical expertise on existing trade barriers.
In February 1996, the Commission launched a new Market Access Strategy,
tactically announced by Sir Leon Brittan as "D-Day for European Trade Policy" to
an audience of major exporting companies (Shaffer 2003: 68). Within DG Trade, a
Market Access Unit was established, the primary role of which was to interact
with business actors to gather information on existing trade barriers. A central
pillar of the work was the maintenance of a Market Access Database (see De
Bièvre 2002: 96-100)[2].
By centralizing information on trade barriers and
involving firms in the collection of information, the EU was hoping to be able
to counter the aggressive private–public partnerships of US trade policy. As the
administration of instruments of commercial defence shows, the Commission
explicitly urged business participation in instruments of commercial defence in
order to gain leverage over its trading partners.
1.3 Trade-offs in multi-level trade lobbying
The study of trade negotiations and of the
administration of instruments of commercial defence illustrates how important
business participation is for the internal and external negotiations of the
European Commission. The solicitation is based on the Commission's hopes of
increasing its technical expertise, its legitimacy, its ability to maintain
consensus among the member states and its leverage in trade negotiations.
However, since Commission officials do not depend on re-election by constituency
interests, firms cannot exert direct pressure on European officials to reinforce
their demands.
Therefore, business access is not automatic; it depends on the
degree to which private actors can offer the elements the Commission is
interested in. Business lobbying on trade is thus marked by a particular
exchange logic, where firms provide expertise and support in order to gain
access to the policy process (Bouwen 2002; Mahoney 2004).
The selective access at the European level creates a two-channel logic for
business lobbyists, which specifies different routes according to the content
that firms seek to defend. Classical protectionism is easier to achieve in
interaction with national governments, while cooperation on the elaboration of
pan-European solutions promises an excellent working relationship with the
European Commission. Pan-European trade policy lobbying can be in support of
liberalization, but it can also consist of regulatory protectionism that does
not discriminate on the grounds of nationality but appeals instead to a greater
Community interest.
In fact, the tendency of the EU to defend a rather liberal external trade policy
is relatively recent. Hanson (1998) argues that member states maintained
national levels of protection in sensitive sectors throughout the 1970s and
1980s, despite the fact that a common commercial policy was enshrined in the
Treaty of Rome. However, through the completion of the internal market, member
states lost their ability to use national policy tools, in particular due to the
legislative instruments available to the Commission in enforcing market
integration (Schmidt 2000). Moreover, EU voting rules make it difficult to
replace national policies with protectionism at the EU level (Hanson 1998: 56).
Consensual decision-making on trade policy means that measures favouring the
sensitive industries in only a few countries will be vetoed by other countries.
Yet, even if the Commission is more liberal than many of the member states,
supranational trade policy initiatives are not always aimed at reducing trade
barriers. In fact, the Commission does not have an a priori tendency to
liberalize; it merely seeks to develop pan-European policy solutions that do not
create cleavages between member states in order to avoid deadlock.
Liberalization happens to be a pan-European solution, but pan-European
regulation is also possible. Many have noted that the liberalization objectives
of the EU often appear like an exercise in international regulation rather than
the complete abandonment of all trade barriers (Winters 2001; Cremona 2001).
Alasdair Young (2002) argues that EU external policy is most accurately
described as an attempt to extend European cooperation to third countries.
Moreover, regulatory harmonization within the single market infrequently creates
"regulatory peaks," as many of the prominent trade disputes between the EU and
third countries illustrate (Young 2004). In other words, even though we should
expect protectionist lobbying to employ national routes and businesses
supporting liberalization to develop partnerships with the European Commission,
we might also find lobbyists defending new kinds of regulatory protectionism
that applies equally across member states.
2 Lobbying for protectionism or liberalization
What does this mean for industry lobbyists and why
is it relevant to distinguish between classic protectionism and pan-European
regulatory protectionism? With few exceptions, European trade policy applies to
all industries alike, so we should expect producers and firms to move their
lobbying efforts to the supranational level. Surprisingly, this is not the case.
By comparing lobbying in agriculture and textiles and clothing, we can see that
protectionist lobbying is only successful when it is supported within the member
states, which is why lobbyists eventually have to concentrate their efforts on
the domestic route. Tellingly, lobbyists targeting the Commission to maintain
import restrictions on textiles and clothing were ignored in the absence of
member state pressure. By contrast, a study of the service trade shows how
business lobbyists have been able to influence the European Commission's
objective once they embraced liberalization as a policy objective. This was easy
for the exporting companies in financial services, but required an important
redefinition of policy demands in telecommunication services, where firms were
not naturally inclined to support liberalization. Distinguishing between the
types of demands can thus help to explain the success or failure of trade policy
lobbying in the EU.
2.1 Resistance to foreign competition: agriculture
and textiles
2.1.1 Agriculture
The agricultural market, one of the most integrated markets in the
European Union, is characterized by a highly centralized structure of
interest representation at the supranational level: the
Comité des organizations professionnelles agricoles (COPA),
founded in 1958. Despite the close, traditionally quasi-corporatist
relations between COPA and the EU Institution on the Common
Agricultural Policy (CAP), lobbying on multilateral trade issues has,
most importantly, passed through national channels. Starting in the
1980s, the crisis of CAP dissolved the consensus between national
agricultural organizations and left space for a more pluralist
organization of agricultural interest groups. Several unified
demonstration in Brussels notwithstanding, the diversification of
interest representation implies that interest representation on
external trade is mediated by the member states (Delorme 2002).
Indeed, during the first years of the
Uruguay Round, national farmer organizations, most notably in France
and Germany, lobbied heavily to ensure that their governments did not
cede ground on agricultural liberalization. In December 1990, strong
internal divisions between the EU member states led to a rejection of
the settlement on agriculture that was supposed to conclude the Uruguay
Round. The Commission hoped to strike a compromise by tying the
multilateral negotiations to a reform of CAP. At the beginning of the
CAP reform process, the Commission had tried to consult with national
farmers' unions, but eventually abandoned its contacts when it realized
that farmers were not willing to move away from the status quo (Vahl
1997: 149). As a consequence, the Commission negotiated directly with
the member states and isolated itself from the critical farmers' union.
In reaction, "farmers' unions simply intensified their lobbying
activities at the member state level" to block CAP reform and
concession in the GATT negotiations (Van den Hoven 2002: 11). Once the
Commission succeeded in a negotiating a compromise with the US at Blair
House in Washington, D.C. in 1992, it was again the French government
which threatened to veto the agreement. Since Germany had shifted its
position to support the Blair House Accord, France ended up in an
isolated position and did not carry through its threat (Balaam 1999:
60).
During the new round of trade talks, opposition to liberalization was
also channelled through national routes. France and Ireland publicly
criticized the Commission's negotiating position during the Doha
ministerial meeting, arguing that the defence of CAP ought to be the
EU's priority for negotiations (Van den Hoven 2002: 19-20). Until the
time of writing, member state disagreement has severely constrained the
Commission's room for manoeuvre in the current negotiations. It is thus
member state opposition, not agricultural lobbying, that explains
development in agricultural trade negotiations. For the Commission,
successful negotiations require neutralizing member state opposition,
not resisting protectionist lobbyists at the supranational level.
2.1.2 Textiles and clothing
As in agriculture, protectionism in
textiles and clothing was achieved through national strategies.
Inversely, when interest groups had to start interacting with the
European Commission, lobbying for protectionism became increasingly
difficult. Protectionism in textiles and clothing dates was enshrined
in four successive Multifibre Arrangements (MFA) from 1974-1994 and
ended with a Uruguay Round Agreement on Textiles and Clothing, which
stipulated that the MFA will be phased out over a ten year period.[3]
Throughout the MFA period, the
orientation of the respective arrangements resulted from intense
intergovernmental bargaining. The relatively moderate EU policy on MFA
I (1974-6) was influenced by the liberal German and Dutch approach,
which resisted US calls for strict protectionism. Since the EU industry
had not yet lost its comparative advantage, the Commission did not want
to intervene. Once the textiles and clothing trade balance
deteriorated, the Committee for the Textile Industries in the European
Community (COMITEXTIL) lobbied heavily in Brussels to draw attention to
the dramatic fall in employment in the sector. Unimpressed and doubting
the reliability of the figures, the Commission maintained that it would
be wrong to give in to these protectionist demands. But things were
different in the Council. Member states felt concerned about the health
of their textiles and clothing industries and announced that the EU
policy should be centred on voluntary export restraints (Ugur 1998:
660). In the difficult economic times of the late 1970s, the UK had
joined France and Ireland's strict protectionist demands, supported
also in Italy. Moderate countries seeking a simple renewal of the MFA
were eventually outnumbered (Aggarwal 1985: 146). Faced with insistent
member states determined to protect what they considered to be their
national interest, the Commission had to switch to a protectionist
trade policy during MFA II and MFA III (1977-85).
The shift towards gradual liberalization
under MFA IV (1986-1994) was tied to the desire of developed countries
to open up trade in services and other new issues (Woolcock 2000: 378).
Yet protectionist lobbying at the European level had not ceased in
1985. COMITEXTIL worked hard to draw attention to the difficult
situation in the sector. Contrary to previous success, the industry
difficulties were seized on by opponents of textile protection to show
that earlier measures had not left the industry better off. As European
countries turned away from Keynesian demand management, member state
support faded. Despite intense lobbying from COMITEXTIL, trade unions
and other textile associations, national representatives on the Article
133 Committee and COREPER were able to work out a compromise in favour
of gradual liberalization. In 1989, moreover, the Commission accepted
the mid-term review of the Uruguay Round, against the insistence of the
textile industry association (Ugur 1998: 663). In 1990s, the Commission
issued a communication underlining that restructuring was appropriate
for the industry and Sir Leon Brittan announced to a shocked industry
audience that "the textile industry is a normal industry" (cited in
Scheffer 2003). Without the backing of the member states, protectionist
lobbying in textiles and clothing at the EU level was a failure.
In a last attempt to secure special
treatment in EU trade policy, industry representatives formed a new
coalition, the European Textile and Clothing Coalition, to avert the
dangers of the new policy orientation in the early 1990s.
Simultaneously, the European Trade Union Committee for Textiles began
to organize meetings and demonstrations. All of these efforts were
ignored by the Commission, which insisted that the industry's problems
had to be resolved by securing a market opening in third countries
(Ugur 1998: 664-5). At the conclusion of the Uruguay Round, the EU had
endorsed the WTO's Agreement on Textiles and Clothing, which was to
phase out all protection until January 2005.
Faced with this new reality, the
textile industry had to reorganize. COMITEXTIL, while other textile
associations founded a new European association in 1995: the European
Apparel and Textile Organization EURATEX. Needing to work with the
Commission in order to affect or delay the integration of sensitive
categories into the WTO agreement, EURATEX launched a review of its
strategy (Scheffer 2003). In contrast to the unsuccessful pressure
lobbying that had characterized earlier protectionist demands, European
industry representatives decided to engage in a more cooperative manner
with the European institutions. As Jacomet (2000: 307) underlines, the
new "interactive lobbying" during the WTO negotiations in the early
1990s had differed sharply from previous activities because lobbyists
had to accept a "trade-off" in the policy demands they could voice:
they exchanged the elimination of the MFA for market access in third
countries. Only by embracing a policy stance centred on market access
did textile lobbyists maintain their contacts with the European
institutions. Indeed, the selection logic of the EU Institutions
forcing European industry representatives to reframe their demands
helps to explain why the EU textile industry became supportive of
foreign market access while their American colleagues continued to
press for strict protectionism. The need to supply a specific kind of
lobbying at the supranational level also becomes clear in the
reorganization of EURATEX. As a result of its internal review, EURATEX
decided to develop a more comprehensive policy "in order to be seen as
relevant partners for policy-makers" (Scheffer 2003: 108). Faced with
very heterogeneous demands from its national associations, EURATEX now
aims not to counteract national lobbying, but to promote synergies
between domestic and European efforts. After the lobbying failures of
the past, EURATEX's approach today is to focus on pan-European stances
to maintain its leadership role at the EU level.
At the end of the Agreement on Textiles and
Clothing's transition period in 2005, European companies complained
vigorously about Chinese competition. Still, companies acknowledged
that the abandonment of the quota system was beyond their control.
Whether they liked it or not, "the affected companies had to accept the
new logic in order to be able to influence the calendar, the modalities
of the new measures or the transition aid" (Jacomet 2004: 5). In the
absence of member state pressure for protection, successful
business–government relations at the supranational level required
accepting the liberalization objective of the European Commission.
2.2 Developing pan-European policy solutions: trade in services
The multilateral General Agreement on Trade
in Services (GATS) that entered into force with the founding of the WTO
in 1995 is often cited as a prime example of business influence over
trade policy. According to many observers, the American financial
service companies and its Coalition for Service Industries played a key
role in bringing the issue onto the international negotiating table
(Drake and Nicolaïdis 1992; Sell 2000; Woll 2004). On the European
side, firms were much less in evidence during the service negotiations
in the Uruguay Round and the sectoral negotiations that followed GATS.
However, the European Commission did consult extensively with industry
representatives in two sectors: financial services and
telecommunication services (Van den Hoven 2002: 10).
2.2.1 Financial services
At the conclusion of the Uruguay Round,
countries agreed to continue sectoral negotiations on financial
services to obtain more detailed liberalization commitments. By the
initial deadline in 1995, the US declared itself unsatisfied with the
existing offers and walked out of the negotiations. Behind the position
of the US government was the frustration of the US private sector,
which had helped to put services on the WTO agenda and now felt that it
was not achieving sufficient market access in foreign countries
(Woolcock 1998).
Faced with the US refusal, the EU assumed
the leadership in the financial service talks and encouraged WTO
members to negotiate an interim agreement without the US in 1995 and to
extend the talks until December 1997. Over the next two years, the
European Commission went out of its way to gain the support of European
financial service firms so it could counter the influence of the US
private sector. Indeed, representatives of "Citicorp, Goldman Sachs,
Merrill Lynch and the insurance companies – particularly the American
Insurance Group and Aetna – established command posts" near the WTO
headquarters and conferred with American negotiators throughout the
financial service talks (Andrews 1997).
Business lobbying comparable to the
activities of the US Coalition of Service Industries was only common in
the United Kingdom, where financial service firms had founded British
Invisibles in 1986, an association to promote the interests of its
members, which later turned into International Financial Services
London. Part of British Invisibles was the working committee LOTIS (the
acronym for Liberalisation Of Trade In Services), which dates back to
the early 1980s (see Wesselius 2001). For the European Commission,
working with these private sector associations was crucial, because
they felt that European firms could best engage the US private sector
in a continued dialogue. Transnational business negotiations began at
the World Economic Forum in Davos, Switzerland in 1996. US, UK and
European financial service representatives met in the office of British
Invisibles and eventually formed the Financial Leaders Group to promote
the interests of the affected firms on both sides of the Atlantic (Sell
2000: 178).
The European Commissioner Sir Leon Brittan
welcomed the creation of this group and worked closely with its
European chair, Andrew Buxton of Barclays Bank (Wesselius 2002: 7). For
the EU negotiators, the Financial Leaders Group was an important
channel through which they hoped to moderate US expectations, in
particular by addressing the concerns of the US private sectors, which
had previously brought the talks to a standstill (Woolcock 1998: 33).
Sir Leon Brittan had long been frustrated with the lack of support
among European companies and tried to encourage them to mobilize around
the issue of international trade liberalization. A representative of
the European service sector remembers:
"At one occasion, he finally invited a series of CEOs for dinner and said s
omething to the effect of 'either you will get organized, or I will take the decisions single-handedly
[4]'."
Contrary to the aggressive lobbying of US
financial service firms, European firms entered negotiations not so
much on their own initiative but, most importantly, in response to the
active encouragement of the European Commission, which was looking for
business support for the difficult financial service talks in the
1990s. The close business–government relationship that developed in the
EU after 1996 was based on the shared aim of liberalizing the sector.
After an unexpected change in the position of the Asian countries
during the currency crisis in 1997, negotiators finally reached an
agreement on December 12, 1997. Yet the cooperation between financial
service firm leaders and the European Commission went even further than
the Financial Service Agreement. In 1998, Sir Leon Brittan asked Andrew
Buxton once again to create a select group of, this time, purely
European business leaders. The European Service Forum, launched on
January 26, 1999, today ensures the Commission's continued support for
the liberalization of service industries and consequentially benefits
from privileged access to trade policy-making at the supranational
level. Had European firms not been supportive of liberalization, it is
highly unlikely that they would have been able to work as closely with
EU policy-makers.
2.2.2 Telecommunications
In telecommunications, the position of
firms was more difficult. European network operators had long benefited
from privileged positions as monopoly providers in their home
countries. The WTO's sectoral negotiations on basic telecommunications
liberalization from 1994-1997 coincided with the liberalization of the
internal EU market. While firms wanted to benefit from foreign market
access once telecommunication markets were liberalized, they were also
concerned about protecting their home market positions. Solicited by
the European Commission, European operators therefore adopted a
pro-liberalization stance in the mid-1990s, which allowed them to
follow and influence the content of the multilateral negotiation in the
WTO while still maintaining close ties to their home governments in
order to defend national interests on specific issues.
In fact, the project of European
telecommunications liberalization had met with very different echoes in
European member states. The United Kingdom and the Nordic countries had
introduced competition in their home markets and pushed actively for
Europe-wide liberalization. Germany, France and the Benelux countries
had initiated more moderate reforms, but had their reservations about
complete liberalization. However, the Southern countries – Italy,
Greece, Spain and Portugal – were not interested in changing their
telecommunication systems (see Noam 1992). The struggle between the
European Commission and the member states over internal
telecommunications liberalization began in 1987 and is recounted
elsewhere in great detail (e.g. Sandholtz 1998; Thatcher 1999b;
Eliassen and Sjøvaag 1999; Holmes and Young 2002). After some judicial
wrangling over EU competences, the Commission was able to propose the
liberalization of telephone services in 1993 and infrastructures in
1994. In 1996, member states reached agreement on implementing
liberalization by January 1, 1998. What is important for an
understanding of the WTO involvement of European network operators is
the consultation efforts made by the European Commission during the
internal liberalization project.
Trying to gain support in the face of
member state resistance, Martin Bangemann, European Commissioner for
Industry, Information Technology and Telecommunications, called
together a group of "wise men," leaders from the telecom industry and
user companies, in order to prepare a communication on the
international competitiveness of European telecommunications. The
consultation procedure is noteworthy, because the Commission dealt with
the senior officials of the national operators directly and encouraged
them to evaluate their position in the internationalizing market. Under
pressure from user companies and competition from liberalized countries
attracting telecommunications-based firms, operators in France and
Germany began to concentrate on reform and internationalization, and
therefore supported the EU liberalization (Thatcher 1999a). With the
backing of the leading European telecommunications providers, the
report issued by the senior official group, the so-called Bangemann
report, was important for encouraging member states onto the route of
liberalization (High-Level Group on the Information Society 1994).
Lobbying on multilateral liberalization was closely connected to internal liberalization. Before 1996,
European network operators were not involved in the sectoral negotiations that had begun in 1994 (Woll 2004).
With the announcement of the 1998 deadline, the European Telecommunication Network Operators association (ETNO),
founded in 1992, was able to gather support for multilateral liberalization as well. A member of the WTO working group recalls:
"We had good
relations with the European Commission. There was no opposition: the
Commission works for Europe and we work for Europe as well.
[5]"
ETNO fully supported the multilateral negotiations and helped the Commission negotiate the Basic Telecom Agreement in 1997.
Indeed, most operators affirm having been
in support of the 1997 agreement and having engaged actively through
their European association throughout the talks. Despite these
declarations, many operators had concerns about losing their national
privileges and so used their national ties to maintain a degree of
control over access to their home markets. Telefónica, the Spanish
operator, for example, insisted on restricting non-EC investment to the
Spanish market, despite the fact that it had become an important
overseas investor in Latin America. When the US criticized the Spanish
position, negotiations over the case turned into bilateral talks
between the Commission and the Spanish government, which had taken up
the highly politicized issue (Niemann 2004: 399). Similarly, network
operators in other countries tried to guarantee national privileges
through the implementation of the EC regulatory framework. Member
states and their regulatory agencies enjoyed immense freedom to
determine interconnection terms and tariffs between networks or to
impose universal service conditions. In contrast to British Telecom,
which received no extra funding for universal service, France Télécom
had the right to obtain compensation (Thatcher 1999a). At the same time
that ETNO was lobbying for reciprocal liberalization of basic
telecommunication services through the WTO, national operators were
seeking to maintain regulatory advantages, i.e. restrictions to foreign
market access, through their national governments.
3 Conclusion
The comparison between agriculture,
textiles and clothing, financial services and telecommunication
services shows that trade policy lobbying in the EU is marked by a
two-channel logic. Protectionism (agriculture) is best defended through
the national route, while lobbying in support of liberalization
(financial services) happens at the supranational level, in particular
through contacts with the European Commission. Companies that seek both
foreign market access and restrictions to competition in their home
markets therefore tend to adopt an ambiguous position, whereby they
support liberalization in general, in order to stay in contact with the
European Commission, but also work through their member states to
maintain national restrictions (telecommunications). Without the
backing of their home governments, protectionist lobbying that impedes
European market integration is unsuccessful at the supranational level
(textiles and clothing). In trade policy, firms thus face a trade-off:
if they want to maintain good relations with the European Commission,
they have to frame their demands in terms of pan-European solutions,
which often means moving away from their immediate interest.
The entrepreneurial role of the European
Commission in creating public–private contacts on trade policy has
several implications. First of all, not just businesses but also other
interest groups, such as environmental or social NGOs, can be solicited
for input into the European trade policy process. As current
consultation demonstrates, the Commission has indeed made an effort to
include an ever broader range of actors in order to increase its
legitimacy and work towards a policy consensus (Woolcock 2000).
However, firms remain the principal source of expertise on trade
barriers and will therefore come into their own whenever the EU seeks
to increase its leverage vis-à-vis trading partners such as the US. It
is therefore important not to overestimate the influence of public
interest groups (De Bièvre and Dür forthcoming), even though the
Commission tries to take their opinion into account through the Civil
Society Dialogue.
Second, the complexity of the strategic
interactions in European trade policy caution against superficial
analyses of trade policy demands in the EU. Because of the two-channel
logic, we should expect to find many firms declaring themselves in
favour of trade liberalization, simply because this ensures them
greater access to the EU trade negotiators. A study of trade
preferences thus needs to distinguish between the strategic positions
of firms and their underlying preferences, which might be much more
ambiguous than the official declarations would lead us to believe.
Finally, the comparison between the various business–government
relations shows that European trade policy lobbying is complex. To
assume that trade policy simply reflects producer demands, as many have
suggested in the case of the US, would be to miss important aspects of
public–private relations in the EU. While firms might capture their
government's positions or even the supranational agenda in certain
cases, the Commission also instrumentalizes European firms and even
affects the content of their lobbying demands. In the end, EU trade
policy results as much from producer demands as it does from the
complex decision-making procedures, the institutional self-interest of
public actors and the power struggles created by their interaction.
References
Aggarwal,
V. K. (1985). Liberal Protectionism: The International Politics of
Organized Textile Trade. Berkeley: University of California Press.
Andrews, E. L. (1997). Agreement to Open Up World Financial Markets Is Reached. New York Times, December 13.
Balaam,
D. N. (1999). Agricultural Trade Policy. In: B. Hocking and S. McGuire
(eds.), Trade Politics: International, Domestic and Regional
Perspectives. London: Routledge, 52-66.
Bhagwati,
J. and Patrick, H. T. (eds.) (1991). Aggressive Unilateralism:
America's 301 Trade Policy and the World Trading System. New York:
Harvester Wheatsheaf.
Bouwen, P. (2002). Corporate Lobbying in the European Union: The Logic
of Access. In: Journal of European Public Policy 9/3: 365-390.
Broscheid, A. and Coen, D. (2003). Insider and Outsider Lobbying in the
European Commission. In: European Union Politics 4/2: 165-189.
Coen, D. (1999). The Impact of U.S. Lobbying Practice on the European
Business-Government Relationship. In: California Management Review
41/4: 27-44.
Coen, D. and Grant, W. (2000). Corporate Political Strategy and Global
Policy: A Case Study of the Transatlantic Business Dialogue. In:
Regulation Initiative Working Paper/42.
Cowles,
M. G. (2001). The Transatlantic Business Dialogue and Domestic
Business-Government Relations. In: J. Caporaso, M. G. Cowles and T.
Risse (eds.), Transforming Europe: Europeanization and Domestic Change.
Ithaca, N.Y.: Cornell University Press.
Cremona,
M. (2001). Neutrality or Discrimination? The WTO, the EU and External
Trade. In: G. De Búrca and J. Scott (eds.), The EU and the WTO: Legal
and Constitutional Issues. Oxford: Hart Publishing, 151-184.
De
Bièvre, D. (2002). The WTO and Domestic Coalitions: The Effects of
Negotiations and Enforcement in the European Union. Ph.D. Dissertation,
Department of Political and Social Sciences, San Domenico di Fiesole:
European University Institute.
De
Bièvre, D. and Dür, A. (2005). Constituency Interests and Delegation in
European and American Trade Policy. In: Comparative Political Studies
38/10: 1271-1296.
De
Bièvre, D. and Dür, A. (forthcoming). Inclusion without Influence?
Civil Society Involvement in European Trade Policy. In: Journal of
Public Policy.
Delorme,
H. (2002). Les agriculteurs et les institutions communautaires: du
corporatisme agricole au lobbyisme agro-alimentaire. In: R. Balme, D.
Chabanet and V. Wright (eds.), L'action collective en Europe. Paris:
Presses de Sciences Po, 313-346.
Drake,
W. J. and Nicolaïdis, K. (1992). Ideas, Interests, and
Institutionalization: Trade in Services and the Uruguay Round. In:
International Organization 46/1: 37-100.
Eliassen, K. A. and Sjøvaag, M. (eds.) (1999). European Telecommunications Liberalisation. London: Routledge.
Frieden,
J. and Martin, L. L. (2002). International Political Economy: Global
and Domestic Interactions. In: I. Katznelson and H. Milner (eds.),
Political Science: The State of the Discipline. New York: W.W. Norton
& Company, 118-146.
Grande,
E. (1996). The State and Interest Groups in a Framework of Multi-Level
Decision-Making: The Case of the European Union. In: Journal of
European Public Policy 3/3: 318-338.
Grant, C. (1994). Delors: Inside the House that Jacques Built. London: Nicholas Brealey Publishing.
Hanson,
B. (1998). What Happened to Fortress Europe? External Trade Policy
Liberalization in the European Union. In: International Organization
52/1: 55-86.
High-Level
Group on the Information Society (1994). Recommendations to the
European Council: Europe and the Global Information Society. May 26.
Brussels: European Commission.
Hoekman, B. M. and Kostecki, M. M. (2001). The Political Economy of the World Trading System. Oxford: Oxford University Press.
Holmes, P. and Young, A. (2002). Liberalizing and Reregulating
Telecommunications in Europe: A Common Framework and Persistent
Differences. In: P. Guerrieri and H.-E. Scharrer (eds.), Trade,
Investment and Competition Policies in the Global Economy: The Case of
the International Telecommunications Regime. Baden-Baden: Nomos,
119-158.
Jacomet, D. (2000). Les stratégies d'entreprises face aux politiques
publiques: le lobbying des producteurs occidentaux et la politique
commerciale internationale dans le textile-habillement. Ph.D. Thesis,
Gestion, Paris: Université Paris IX - Dauphine.
Jacomet,
D. (2004). Les changements induits par l'intégration européenne et la
mondialisation sur la stratégie d'influence des entreprises: le cas de
l'Union des Industries Textiles (UIT). Paper presented at the
conference "Interest groups in the 21st century in France and Europe,"
Paris, September 24-25.
Johnson, M. (1998). European Community Trade Policy and the Article 113
Committee. London: Royal Institute of International Affairs.
Mahoney,
C. (2004). The Power of Institutions: State and Interest Group Activity
in the European Union. In: European Union Politics 5/4: 441-466.
Meunier,
S. (2000a). EU Trade Policy: The Exclusive versus Shared Competence
Debate. In: M. G. Cowles and M. Smith (eds.), The State of the European
Union: Risks, Reform, Resistance, and Revival. Oxford: Oxford
University Press, 325-346.
Meunier, S. (2000b). What Single Voice? European Institutions and
EU–U.S. Trade Negotiations. In: International Organizations 54/1:
103-136.
Meunier,
S. and Nicolaïdis, K. (1999). Who Speaks for Europe? The Delegation of
Trade Authority in the European Union. In: Journal of Common Market
Studies 37/3: 477-501.
Niemann,
A. (2004). Between communicative action and strategic action: the
Article 113 Committee and the negotiations on the WTO Basic
Telecommunications Agreement. In: Journal of European Public Policy
11/3: 379-407.
Noam, E. (1992). Telecommunications in Europe. New York: Oxford University Press.
Sandholtz,
W. (1998). The Emergence of a Supranational Telecommunications Regime.
In: W. Sandholtz and A. Stone Sweet (eds.), European Integration and
Supranational Governance. Oxford: Oxford University Press.
Scheffer,
M. (2003). Textiles. In: J. Greenwood (ed.), The Challenge of Change in
EU Business Associations. New York: Palgrave, 103-114.
Schmidt,
S. K. (2000). Only an Agenda Setter? The European Commission's Power
over the Council of Ministers. In: European Union Politics 1/1: 37-61.
Sell,
S. K. (2000). Big Business and the New Trade Agreements: The Future of
the WTO. In: R. Stubbs and G. R. D. Underhill (eds.), Political Economy
and the Changing Global Order. Oxford: Oxford University Press.
Shaffer,
G. C. (2003). Defending Interests: Public-Private Partnerships in WTO
Litigation. Washington, D.C.: Brookings Institution Press.
Thatcher, M. (1999a). The Europeanisation of Regulation: The Case of Telecommunications. In: EUI Working Papers 99/22.
Thatcher,
M. (1999b). The Politics of Telecommunications: National Institutions,
Convergence, and Change in Britain and France. Oxford: Oxford
University Press.
Ugur,
M. (1998). Explaining Protectionism and Liberalization in European
Union Trade Policy: The Case of Textiles and Clothing. In: Journal of
European Public Policy 5/4: 652-70.
Vahl,
R. (1997). Leadership in Disguise: The Role of the European Commission
in EC Decision-Making on Agriculture in the Uruguay Round. Hants, UK:
Ashgate.
Van
den Hoven, A. (2002). Interest Group Influence on Trade Policy in a
Multilevel Polity: Analysing the EU Position at the Doha WTO
Ministerial Conference. In: EUI Working Papers 2002/67.
Wesselius, E. (2001). Liberalisation of Trade in Services: Corporate Power at Work. GATSwatch Background Paper.
Wesselius, E. (2002). Behind GATS 2000: Corporate Power at Work. In: Transnational Institute Briefing Series 2002/6.
Winters,
L. A. (2001). European Union Trade Policy: Actually or Just Nominally
Liberal? In: H. Wallace (ed.), Interlocking Dimensions of European
Integration. New York: Palgrave, 25-44.
Woll,
C. (2004). The Politics of Trade Preferences: Business Lobbying on
Service Trade in the United States and the European Union. Ph.D.
Dissertation, Political Science, Paris / Cologne: Institut d'Etudes
Politiques de Paris / Universität zu Köln.
Woll,
C. (2006). Lobbying in the European Union: From Sui Generis to a
Comparative Perspective. In: Journal of European Public Policy 13/3:
456-469.
Woolcock, S. (1998). Liberalisation of Financial Services.
Woolcock,
S. (2000). European Trade Policy: Global Pressures and Domestic
Constraints. In: H. Wallace and W. Wallace (eds.), Policy-making in the
European Union. Oxford: Oxford University Press.
Young,
A. (2002). Extending European Cooperation: The European Union and the
"New" International Trade Agenda. Manchester: Manchester University
Press.
Young,
A. (2004). The Incidental Fortress: The Single European Market and
World Trade. In: Journal of Common Market Studies 42/2: 393-414.
Endnotes
1
The EU, in turn, brought only two, both jointly with the US,
against third countries (Shaffer 2003: 67-8).
2
Available from within the Eu at http://mkaccdb.eu.int.
3
For an historical overview, see Aggarwal (1985) and Hoekman and Kostecki
(2001: 226-231).
4
Interview with the author in Brussels, November 13, 2002.
5
Interview with the author in Brussels, September 3, 2003.
Copyright © 2006 Cornelia Woll No part of this publication may be
reproduced or transmitted without permission in writing from the author.
Jegliche Vervielfältigung und Verbreitung, auch auszugsweise, bedarf der
Zustimmung des Autors. MPI für Gesellschaftsforschung,
Paulstr. 3, 50676 Köln, Germany
|